Published and Accepted Papers
Management Science (Published online on November 8, 2024)
SSRN link here
Factor data from the original paper
Conferences: Triangle Macro-Finance Workshop (2022), China International Conference in Finance (2022), University of Southern California Macro-Finance Workshop (2022), Midwest Finance Association (2021), Luso-Brazilian Finance Meeting (2021)
Prominent factor models are based on tradable factors that do not represent theoretically relevant risks. To address this issue, we develop a factor model that captures the risks to long-term investors present in the Intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM). Empirically, we construct intertemporal risk factors as long-short portfolios based on stock exposures to dividend yield and realized variance. These tradable factors mimic news to long-term expected returns and volatility, and they offset part of the marginal utility increase in recessions induced by wealth declines. Our intertemporal factor model estimation implies significant risk prices that are consistent with the ICAPM restrictions under moderate risk aversion. Moreover, our model performs well relative to previous factor models in terms of its tangency Sharpe ratio and its pricing of key test assets, including single stocks, industry portfolios, and portfolios sorted on risk exposures and lagged anomalies.
The Accounting Review (Published online on February 14, 2024)
SSRN link here
Best Paper in Asset Pricing: 2019 SFS Cavalcade Asia-Pacific
Winner: 2019 Chicago Quantitative Alliance Academic Paper Competition
Conferences: SFS Cavalcade Asia-Pacific (2019), Midwest Finance Association (2019), Chicago Quantitative Alliance (2019), Miami Behavioral Finance Conference (2018, PhD poster session), Illinois Economic Association (2018)
I use a novel decomposition to estimate information and bias components from the returns implied by analyst price targets and provide evidence that prices simultaneously under-react to information and over-react to bias. Price reactions to information are permanent, and prices drift in the direction of their initial reaction for up to 12 months. Price reactions to bias are transitory, and prices reverse their initial reaction after about three months. Price reactions are relatively efficient. Approximately 85 percent of the total price reaction to information occurs during price target announcement months. Market participants are able to mostly (but not fully) debias analyst-expected returns before incorporating them into prices, with the announcement-month reaction to bias being relatively weak at about 15 percent of its reaction to information. A trading strategy analysis implies that mispricing induced by bias is only about one-third of that implied by prior research.
Management Science (Published online on November 22, 2023)
SSRN link here (includes Internet Appendix)
Risk premium data from the original paper
NEW (2023): Updated risk premium data through Dec/2022. We use updated data to re-estimate preference parameters according to the methodology in the paper, and provide the corresponding updated unrestricted and restricted bounds through December, 2022.
Conferences and Workshops: American Finance Association (AFA) Annual Meeting (2022), Midwest Finance Association (2022), FMA Conference on Derivatives and Volatility (2021), Northern Finance Association (NFA) Annual Meeting (2021), Wabash Conference (2021), Virtual Derivatives Workshop (03-24-2021)
We develop a methodology to decompose the conditional market risk premium and risk premia on higher-order moments of excess market returns into risk premia related to contingent claims on down, up, and moderate market returns. The decomposition exploits information about the risk-neutral market return distribution embedded in option prices but does not depend on assumptions about the functional form of investor preferences or about the market return distribution. The total market risk premium is highly time-varying, as are the contributions from downside, upside, and central risk. Time series variation in risk premia associated with each region is primarily driven by variation in risk prices associated with the probability of entering each region at short horizons, but it is primarily driven by variation in risk quantities at longer horizons. Analogous decompositions implied by prominent representative agent models generally fail to match the dynamic risk premium behavior implied by the data. Our results provide a set of new empirical facts regarding the drivers of conditional risk premia and identify new challenges for representative agent models.
Journal of Financial Economics 137 (3), September 2020, Pages 752-786.
SSRN link here (includes Internet Appendix).
Bounds data from the paper
NEW (2023): Updated bounds data through Feb/2023. We use updated data to re-estimate preference parameters according to the methodology in the paper, and provide the corresponding updated unrestricted and restricted bounds through February, 2023.
Application by the Bank of England: The bounds are currently (as of 2025) being used as part of the Bank of England's risk monitoring toolkit. See the following article for an example its application.
We derive lower and upper bounds on the conditional expected excess market return that are related to risk-neutral volatility, skewness, and kurtosis indexes. The bounds can be calculated in real time using a cross section of option prices. The bounds require a no-arbitrage assumption, but do not depend on distributional assumptions about market returns or past observations. The bounds are highly volatile, positively skewed, and fat tailed. They imply that the term structure of expected excess holding period returns is decreasing during turbulent times and increasing during normal times, and that the expected excess market return is on average 5.2%.
We also derive closed-form expressions for any physical moment of the excess market return (e.g., mean, variance, skewness, kurtosis, etc.) when the functional form of the utility is specified. We provide closed-form expressions for the SDF obtained when a representative agent has CARA, CRRA, and HARA utilities. In these cases, we also derive closed-form expressions for physical moments of the excess market return. Bounds are not needed. Although we derive these closed-form expressions, our bounds are for the general case when the utility function and SDF are not known.